During the Q&A session, enquiries focused on the Eurozone crisis and a slowdown in China, but I wanted to return to the tepid U.S. growth outlook. Hoping that my logic had missed something, I asked for the journalist’s thoughts on potential sources of growth, which could help us escape the purgatory of 2% gains in output. My question centered on three premises: after a recession or a crisis, exports often lead countries into the promised land of recovery. Alas, compared to other industrialized powers, the U.S. is an island when it comes to foreign trade. Similarly, manufacturing, often of goods meant for export, is another source of early stage growth. But again, manufacturing has become a smaller slice of the U.S. economic pie, and alone is no longer sufficient to dramatically move the dial. Lastly, with these two realities having been abundantly clear to policy makers over the past two decades, the entire country relied upon a housing boom for recent incremental growth. We know how that ended. With foreclosure rates high, consumers deleveraging and excess housing inventory lurking in the shadows of bank balance sheets, we won’t be riding that pony again anytime soon.
As I laid out my rationale,
fellow guest snarled in my direction. How dare I, especially in Boulder, voice
the apostasy of not acknowledging the infallibility of the message carried in the
torrent of political ads of the incipient election season? We are on the cusp
of a brave new world after all. One where all Americans happily construct
windmill turbines or develop algorithms….since we are so good in math… to
manage the nation’s new smart grid. And there shall be a Prius…or better yet, a
Chevy Volt….in every garage and an organic chicken in every pot. Fortunately
the speaker was a bit more understanding, although not heartening, in his
response. He simply said that the United States, throughout its history has had
the ability to reinvigorate, if not reinvent, its economy much more effectively
than other countries. Nice words, but I
was hoping for something a bit more tangible. It also did little to stop the
hisses aimed towards me.
To buttress my defense,
albeit ex post facto, this posting will dig slightly deeper into the three
growth sources around which I framed my question. The issue is of import given the backdrop in
diminishing U.S. economic growth trends registered over the past few decades.
As seen below, from the post WWII era through 1980 (and this includes the lean
1970’s) U.S. GDP growth averaged over 3.5%. By 1980 through the beginning of
the housing crisis, average growth had dipped to nearly 3%. Even when excluding
the nadir of the crisis, growth has only averaged 1.5% during this so-called
recovery. Usually, this is the period when GDP exceeds the trend as consumers and businesses release pent up
demand caused by delaying purchases during the downturn. Since the consumer
powers 70% of the economy, and he is either deleveraging, marginally attached
to the workforce or cannot get credit, we cannot expect John Q. Public to
rescue us this time.
But what of manufacturing?
No secret here, but services dominate the U.S. economy, comprising 80% of GDP.
Over the past 30 years, manufacturing as a share of GDP has dipped from 21% to under
15%. Consequently, manufacturing jobs have atrophied. In 1971 manufacturing jobs
comprised 24% of non-farm payrolls. Today it is 9%. In absolute numbers, that
is over 5.3 million jobs lost (a 30% decline). Between 2007 and 2009 the market
shed 2.5 million manufacturing jobs alone. One may expect many of those losses to be
cyclical rather than solely attributable to the structural decline, but since the
beginning of 2010, less than 500 thousand of those positions have returned.
Even when comprising a
smaller slice of GDP, manufacturing jobs are important contributors to economic
growth, as many of the positions are reserved for high wage, skilled workers,
who then spend their earnings on meals out, trips to Vegas and titanium-level
cable TV packages. Furthermore, service companies piggy-back on manufacturing
growth by providing them insurance, payroll services, software and airline
tickets. So yes, there is a magnifier effect, but with only 9% of workers
involved in the sector, the virtuous circle of a factory rebound felt
throughout the economy is not as large as it once was. This is especially true
as U.S. manufacturing is becoming more productive, which is a euphemism for automation.
This means opportunities for highly-trained workers….but we’ll just need fewer
of them.
With exports, as with
manufacturing, there is good and bad. The good is that the U.S. still ranks as
the world’s number three exporter. And like number two, Germany, we sell the
high value-added capital goods that are in demand by both emerging and
developed countries to drive productivity higher. Furthermore, we remain the
world leader in business services exports. But like with manufacturing, the
slice of the U.S. GDP pie is not large, especially when compared to other
industrialized nations (see chart below). This is important in this economic environment
as the policy makers’ playbook often leans of promoting exports to pull oneself
out of recession, especially when targeting regions of the world that did not
endure a downturn. Indeed, during the past few years, manufacturing exports to
emerging markets have been a bright spot, but as subpar GDP growth and
lackluster job gains have illustrated, these segments are not sufficient to
have substantial spillover effects into the broader economy and overcome
countervailing forces.
Chief among these headwinds
is the hangover of the housing crisis, which ironically, was the growth elixir
of the preceding decade. But as a wise investor once stated, a strong housing
market should be a consequence of a
robust economy, not a source of it. We’ll save the nuts and bolts of the housing
market for another posting. For today, it is only necessary to recognize that
turbocharged and distorted housing demand, thanks to cheap credit and low
standards, caused residential construction’s share of economic output to rise
dramatically. From 1980 to 2000 residential construction averaged 4.2% of GDP.
That climbed to 6.3% by 2005. More tellingly, from 2003 to 2005, home building
on average accounted for 13% of the nation’s growth in each period. Throw in
the knock off effects of outfitting the homes with carpet, furniture and flat
screen TVs, not to mention houses being turned into ATM machines to purchase
cars and vacations, one can see the tremendous impact the housing boom had on the
broader economy. But what comes up, must come down. Mean reversion is such a
callous principle. In 13 of the most recent 25 quarters, home construction has
been a net negative to overall GDP growth.
With nearly 30% of mortgaged homes underwater and credit standards
tight, we cannot look to housing to again rescue us as it did after the 2001
recession.
No comments:
Post a Comment